home *** CD-ROM | disk | FTP | other *** search
- Subject: 89-1452 & 89-1453 -- OPINION, MOBIL OIL EXPLORATION v. UNITED DISTRIBUTION
-
- NOTICE: This opinion is subject to formal revision before publication in
- the preliminary print of the United States Reports. Readers are requested
- to notify the Reporter of Decisions, Supreme Court of the United States,
- Washington, D. C. 20543, of any typographical or other formal errors, in
- order that corrections may be made before the preliminary print goes to
- press.
- SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
-
-
- Nos. 89-1452 and 89-1453
-
-
- MOBIL OIL EXPLORATION & PRODUCING SOUTHEAST INC., et al., PETITIONERS v.
- 89-1452
- UNITED DISTRIBUTION COMPANIES et al.
-
-
- FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMIS-
- SION, PETITIONER
- v.
- 89-1453
- UNITED DISTRIBUTION COMPANIES et al.
-
-
- on writs of certiorari to the united states court of appeals for the fifth
- circuit
-
- [January 8, 1991]
-
-
-
- Justice White delivered the opinion of the Court.
-
- These cases involve the validity of two orders, No. 451 and No. 451-A,
- promulgated by the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (Commission) to
- make substantial changes in the national market for natural gas. On
- petitions for review, a divided panel of the Court of Appeals for the Fifth
- Circuit vacated the orders as exceeding the Commission's authority under
- the Natural Gas Policy Act of 1978 (NGPA), 92 Stat. 3352, 15 U. S. C. MDRV
- 3301 et seq. 885 F. 2d 209 (1989). In light of the economic interests at
- stake, we granted certiorari and consolidated the cases for briefing and
- oral argument. 496 U. S. --- (1990). For the reasons that follow, we
- reverse and sustain the Commission's orders in their entirety.
- I
- The Natural Gas Act of 1938 (NGA), 52 Stat. 821, 15 U. S. C. MDRV 717
- et seq. was Congress' first attempt to establish nationwide natural gas
- regulation. Section 4(a) mandated that the present Commission's
- predecessor, the Federal Power Commission {1}, ensure that all rates and
- charges requested by a natural gas company for the sale or transportation
- of natural gas in interstate commerce be "just and reasonable." 15 U. S.
- C. MDRV 717c(a). Section 5(a) further provided that the Commission order a
- "just and reasonable rate, charge, classification, rule, regulation,
- practice, or contract" connected with the sale or transportation of gas
- whenever it determined that any of these standards or actions were "unjust"
- or "unreasonable." 15 U. S. C. 717d(a).
- Over the years the Commission adopted a number of different approaches
- in applying the NGA's "just and reasonable" standard. See Public Serv.
- Comm'n of N. Y. v. Mid-Louisiana Gas Co., 463 U. S. 319, 327-331 (1983).
- Initially the Commission, construing the NGA to regulate gas sales only at
- the downstream end of interstate pipelines, proceeded on a
- company-by-company basis with reference to the historical costs each
- pipeline operator incurred in acquiring and transporting gas to its
- customers. The Court upheld this approach in FPC v. Hope Natural Gas Co.,
- 320 U. S. 591 (1944), explaining that the NGA did not bind the Commission
- to "any single formula or combination of formulae in determining rates."
- Id., at 602.
- The Commission of necessity shifted course in response to our decision
- in Phillips Petroleum Co. v. Wisconsin, 347 U. S. 672 (1954). Phillips
- interpreted the NGA to require that the Commission regulate not just the
- downstream rates charged by large interstate pipeline concerns, but also
- upstream sales rates charged by thousands of independent gas producers.
- Id., at 682. Faced with the regulatory burden that resulted, the
- Commission eventually opted for an "area rate" approach for the independent
- producers while retaining the company-by-company method for the interstate
- pipelines. First articulated in 1960, the area rate approach established a
- single rate schedule for all gas produced in a given region based upon
- historical production costs and rates of return. See Statement of General
- Policy No. 61-1, 24 F. P. C. 818 (1960). Each area rate schedule included
- a twotiered price ceiling: the lower ceiling for gas prices established in
- "old" gas contracts and a higher ceiling for gas prices set in "new"
- contracts. Id., at 819. The new two-tier system was termed "vintage
- pricing" or "vintaging." Vintaging rested on the premise that the higher
- ceiling price would provide incentives for the production of new gas that
- would be superfluous for old gas already flowing because "price could not
- serve as an incentive, and since any price above historical costs, plus an
- appropriate return, would merely confer windfalls." Permian Basin Area
- Rate Cases, 390 U. S. 747, 797 (1968). The balance the Commission hoped to
- strike was the development of gas production through the "new" gas ceilings
- while ensuring continued protection of consumers through the "old" gas
- price limits. At the same time the Commission anticipated that the
- differences in price levels would be "reduced and eventually eliminated as
- subsequent experience brings about revisions in the prices in the various
- areas." Statement of General Policy, supra, at 818. We upheld the vintage
- pricing system in Permian Basin, holding that the courts lacked the
- authority to set aside any Commission rate that is within the " `zone of
- reasonableness.' " 390 U. S., at 797 (citation ommitted).
- By the early 1970's, the two-tiered area rate approach no longer
- worked. Inadequate production had led to gas shortages which in turn had
- prompted a rapid rise in prices. Accordingly, the Commission abandoned
- vintaging in favor of a single national rate designed to encourage
- production. Just and Reasonable National Rates for Sales of Natural Gas,
- 51 F. P. C. 2212 (1974). Refining this decision, the Commission prescribed
- a single national rate for all gas drilled after 1972, thus rejecting an
- earlier plan to establish different national rates for succeeding biennial
- vintages. Just and Reasonable National Rates for Sales of Natural Gas, 52
- F. P. C. 1604, 1615 (1974). But the single national pricing scheme did not
- last long either. In 1976 the Commission reinstated vin taging with the
- promulgation of Order No. 770. National Rates for Jurisdictional Sales of
- Natural Gas, 56 F. P. C. 509 (1976). At about the same time, in Order No.
- 749, the Commission also consolidated a number of the old vintages for
- discrete areas into a single nationwide category for all gas already under
- production before 1973. Just and Reasonable National Rates for Sales of
- Natural Gas, 54 F. P. C. 3090 (1975). Despite this consolidation, the
- Commission's price structure still contained 15 different categories of old
- gas, each with its own ceiling price. Despite all these efforts, moreover,
- severe shortages persisted in the interstate market because low ceiling
- prices for interstate gas sales fell considerably below prices the same gas
- could command in intrastate markets, which were as yet unregulated.
- Congress responded to these ongoing problems by enacting the NGPA, the
- statute that controls this controversy. See Mid-Louisiana Gas Co., supra,
- at 330-331. The NGPA addressed the problem of continuing shortages in
- several ways. First, it gave the Commission the authority to regulate
- prices in the intrastate market as well as the interstate market. See
- Transcontinental Gas Pipe Line Corp. v. State Oil and Gas Bd. of Miss., 474
- U. S. 409, 420-421 (1986) (Transco). Second, to encourage production of
- new reserves, the NGPA established higher price ceilings for new and
- hard-to-produce gas as well as a phased deregulation scheme for these types
- of gas. 15 102, 103, 105, 107 and 108; 15 U. S. C. 15 3312, 3313, 3315,
- 3317, 3318. Finally, to safeguard consumers, 15 104 and 106 carried over
- the vintage price ceilings that happened to be in effect for old gas when
- the NGPA was enacted while mandating that these be adjusted for inflation.
- 15 U. S. C. 15 3314 and 3316. Congress, however, recognized that some of
- these vintage price ceilings "may be too low and authorize[d] the
- Commission to raise [them] whenever traditional NGA principles would
- dictate a higher price." Mid-Louisiana Gas, supra, at 333. In particular,
- 15 104(b)(2) and 106(c) provided that the Commission "may, by rule or
- order, prescribe a maximum lawful ceiling price, applicable to any first
- sale of natural gas (or category thereof, as determined by the Commission)
- otherwise subject to the preceding provisions of this section." 15 U. S.
- C. 15 3314(b)(2) and 3316(c). The only conditions that Congress placed on
- the Commission were first, that the new ceiling be higher than the ceiling
- set by the statute itself and second, that it be "just and reasonable"
- within the meaning of the NGA. 15 U. S. C. 15 3314(b)(1), 3316(a).
- The new incentives for production of new and difficult-toproduce gas
- transformed the gas shortages of the 1970s into gas surpluses during the
- 1980s. One result was serious market distortions. The higher new gas
- price ceilings prevented the unexpected oversupply from translating into
- lower consumer prices since the lower, vintage gas ceilings led to the
- premature abandonment of old gas reserves. App. 32-36. Accordingly, the
- Secretary of Energy in 1985 formally recommended that the Commission issue
- a notice of proposed rulemaking to revise the old gas pricing system. 50
- Fed. Reg. 48540 (1985). After conducting two days of public hearings and
- analyzing approximately 113 sets of comments, the Commission issued the two
- orders under dispute in this case: Order No. 451 promulgated in June 1986,
- 51 Fed. Reg. 22168 (1986); and Order No. 451-A, promulgated in December
- 1986, which reaffirmed the approach of its predecessor while making certain
- modifications. {2} 51 Fed. Reg. 46762 (1986).
- The Commission's orders have three principal components. First, the
- Commission collapsed the 15 existing vintage price categories of old gas
- into a single classification and established an alternative maximum price
- for a producer of gas in that category to charge, though only to a willing
- buyer. The new ceiling was set at $2.57 per million BTUs, a price equal to
- the highest of the ceilings then in effect for old gas (that having the
- most recent, post-1974, vintage) adjusted for inflation. 51 Fed. Reg.
- 22183-22185 (1986); see 18 CFR MDRV 271.402(c)(3)(iii) (1986). When
- established the new ceiling exceeded the then-current market price for old
- gas. The Commission nonetheless concluded that this new price was "just
- and reasonable" because, among other reasons, it generally approximated the
- replacement cost of gas based upon the current cost of finding new gas
- fields, drilling new wells, and producing new gas. See Shell Oil Co. v.
- FPC, 520 F. 2d 1061 (CA5 1975) (holding that replacement cost formula
- appropriate for establishing "just and reasonable" rates under the NGA).
- In taking these steps, the Commission noted that the express and
- unambiguous terms of 15 104(b)(2) and 106(c) gave it specific authorization
- to raise old gas prices so long as the resulting ceiling met the just and
- reasonable requirement. 51 Fed. Reg., at 22179.
- The second principal feature of the orders establishes a "Good Faith
- Negotiation" (GFN) procedure that producers must follow before they can
- collect a higher price from current pipeline customers. 18 CFR MDRV
- 270.201 (1986). The GFN process consists of several steps. Initially, a
- producer may request a pipeline to nominate a price at which the pipeline
- would be willing to continue purchasing old gas under any existing
- contract. MDRV 270.201(b)(1). At the same time, however, this request is
- also deemed to be an offer by the producer to release the purchaser from
- any contract between the parties that covers the sale of old gas. MDRV
- 270.201(b)(4). In response, the purchaser can both nominate its own price
- for continuing to purchase old gas under the contracts specified by the
- purchaser and further, request that the producer nominate a price at which
- the producer would be willing to continue selling any gas, old or new,
- covered under any contracts specified by the purchaser that cover at least
- some old gas. If the parties cannot come to terms, the producer can either
- continue sales at the old price under existing contracts or abandon its
- existing obligations so long as it has executed a new contract with another
- purchaser and given its old customer 30-days' notice. 15 157.301,
- 270.201(c)(1), (e)(4). The Commission's chief rationale for the GFN
- process was a fear that automatic collection of the new price by producers
- would lead to market disruption given the existence of numerous gas
- contracts containing indefinite price-escalation clauses tied to whatever
- ceiling the agency established. 51 Fed. Reg., at 22204. The Commission
- further concluded that NGA MDRV 7(b), which establishes a "due hearing"
- requirement before abandonments could take place, did not prevent it from
- promulgating an across the board rule rather than engage in case-by-case
- adjudication. 15 U. S. C. MDRV 717f(b).
- Finally, the Commission rejected suggestions that it undertake
- completely to resolve the issue of take-or-pay provisions in certain
- natural gas contracts in the same proceeding in which it addressed old gas
- pricing. {3} The Commission explained that it was already addressing the
- take-or-pay problem in its Order 436 proceedings. It further pointed out
- that the GFN procedure, in allowing purchaser to propose new higher prices
- for old gas in return for renegotiation of takeor-pay obligations, would
- help resolve many take-or-pay disputes. The Commission also reasoned that
- the expansion of old gas reserves resulting from its orders would reduce
- new gas prices and thus reduce the pipelines' overall take-or-pay exposure.
- 51 Fed. Reg., at 22174-22175, 22183, 22196-22197, 46783-46784, 22197.
- A divided panel of the Court of Appeals for the Fifth Circuit vacated
- the orders on the ground that the Commission had exceeded its statutory
- authority. The court first concluded that Congress did not intend to give
- the Commission the authority to set a single ceiling price for old gas
- under 15 104(b)(2) and 106(c). The court also dismissed the ceiling price
- itself as unreasonable since it was higher than the spot market price when
- the orders were issued and so amounted to "de facto deregulation." 885 F.
- 2d, at 218-222. Second, the court rejected the GFN procedure on the basis
- that the Commission lacked the authority to provide for across the board,
- preauthorized abandonment under MDRV 7(b). Id., at 221-222. Third, the
- court chided the Commission for failing to seize the opportunity to resolve
- the take-or-pay issue, although it did acknowledge that the Commission was
- addressing that matter on remand from the District of Columbia Circuit's
- decision in Associated Gas Distributors v. FERC, 824 F. 2d 981 (CADC 1987),
- cert. denied, 485 U. S. 1006 (1988). The dissent disagreed with all three
- conclusions, observing that the majority should have deferred to the
- Commission as the agency Congress delegated to regulate natural gas. 885
- F. 2d, at 226-235 (Brown, J., dissenting). We now reverse and sustain the
- Commission's orders.
- II
- Section 104 (a) provides that the maximum price for old gas should be
- computed as provided in MDRV 104(b). {4} The general rule under MDRV
- 104(b)(1) is that each category of old gas would be priced as it was prior
- to the enactment of the NGPA, but increased over time in accordance with an
- inflation formula. This was the regime that obtained under the NGPA until
- the issuance of the orders at issue here. Section 104(b)(2), however,
- plainly gives the Commission authority to change this regulatory scheme
- applicable to old gas:
-
- "The Commission may, by rule or order, prescribe a maximum lawful
- ceiling price, applicable to any first sale of any natural gas (or category
- thereof, as determined by the Commission) otherwise subject to the
- preceding provisions of this section, if such price is --
- "(A) higher than the maximum lawful price which would otherwise be
- applicable under such provisions; and
- "(B) just and reasonable within the meaning of the Natural Gas Act [15
- U. S. C. MDRV 717 et seq.]." 15 U. S. C. 15 3314(b)(2) and 3316(c).
-
-
- Nothing in these provisions prevents the Commission from either
- increasing the ceiling price for multiple old gas vintages or from setting
- the ceiling price applicable to each vintage at the same level. To the
- contrary, the statute states that the Commission may increase the ceiling
- price for "any natural gas (or category thereof, as determined by the
- Commission)." Likewise, 15 104(b)(2) allows the Commission to "prescribe a
- ceiling price" applicable to any natural gas category. Insofar as "any"
- encompasses "all," this language enables the Commission to set a single
- ceiling price for every category of old gas. As we have stated in similar
- contexts, "[i]f the statute is clear and unambiguous, `that is the end of
- the matter, for the court, as well as the agency, must give effect to the
- unambiguously expressed intent of Congress.' " Sullivan v. Stroop, 496 U.
- S. --- (1990) (quoting K Mart Corp. v. Cartier, Inc., 486 U. S. 281, 291
- (1988).
- Respondents counter that the structure of the NGPA points to the
- opposite conclusion. Specifically, they contend that Congress could not
- have intended to allow the Commission to collapse all old gas vintages
- under a single price where the NGPA created detailed incentives for new and
- difficultto-produce gas on one hand, yet carefully preserved the old gas
- vintaging scheme on the other. Brief for Respondents 33-37. We disagree.
- The statute's bifurcated approach implies no more than that Congress found
- the need to encourage new gas production sufficiently pressing to deal with
- the matter directly, but was content to leave old gas pricing within the
- discretion of the Commission to alter as conditions warranted. The plain
- meaning of MDRV 104(b)(2) confirms this view.
- Further, the Commission's decision to set a single ceiling fully
- accords with the two restrictions that the NGPA does establish. With
- respect to the first, the requirement that a ceiling price be "higher than"
- the old vintage ceilings carried over from the NGA does nothing to prevent
- the Commission from consolidating existing categories and setting one price
- equivalent to the highest previous ceiling. 15 U. S. C. 15 3314(b)(2)(A)
- and 3316(c)(A). With respect to the second, collapsing the old vintages
- also comports with the mandate that price ceilings be "just and reasonable
- within the meaning of the Natural Gas Act." 15 U. S. C. 15 3314(b)(2)(B)
- and 3316(c)(B).
- Far from binding the Commission, the "just and reasonable" requirement
- accords it broad ratemaking authority that its decision to set a single
- ceiling does not exceed. The Court has repeatedly held that the just and
- reasonable standard does not compel the Commission to use any single
- pricing formula in general or vintaging in particular. FPC v. Hope Natural
- Gas Co., 320 U. S. 591, 602 (1944); FPC v. Natural Gas Pipeline Co., 315 U.
- S. 575, 586 (1942); Permian Basin, 390 U. S., at 776-777; FPC v. Texaco,
- Inc., 417 U. S. 380, 386-89 (1974); Mobil Oil Corp. v. FPC, 417 U. S. 283,
- 308 (1974). Courts of appeal have also consistently affirmed the
- Commission's use of a replacement cost-based method under the NGA. E. g.
- Shell Oil Co. v. FPC, 520 F. 2d 1061, 1082-1083 (CA5 1975), cert. denied,
- 426 U. S. 941 (1976); American Public Gas Assn. v. FPC, 567 F. 2d 1016,
- 1059 (CADC 1977), cert. denied, 435 U. S. 907 (1978). By incorporating the
- "just and reasonable" standard into the NPGA, Congress clearly meant to
- preserve the pricing flexibility the Commission had historically exercised
- under the NGPA. See Merrill Lynch, Pierce, Fenner & Smith, Inc. v. Curran,
- 456 U. S. 353, 378-382 (1982). In employing a replacement cost formula,
- the Commission did no more than what it had previously done under the NGA:
- collapse vintage categories together because the replacement cost for
- natural gas is the same regardless of when it was placed in production.
- See Opinion No. 749, Just and Reasonable National Rates for Sales of
- Natural Gas, 54 FPC 3090 (1975), aff'd sub nom. Tenneco Oil Co. v. FERC,
- 571 F. 2d 834 (CA5), cert. dismissed, 439 U. S. 801 (1978). {5}
- Respondents contend that even if the statute allows the Commission to
- set a single old gas ceiling, the particular ceiling it has set is unjustly
- and impermissibly high. They first argue that the Commission conceded that
- actual collection of the new price would not be just and therefore
- established the GFN procedures as a requisite safeguard. The Commission
- correctly denies having made any such concession. In its orders, in its
- briefs, and at oral argument, the agency has been at pains to point out
- that its ceiling price, which was no higher than the highest of the
- ceilings then applicable to old gas, falls squarely within the "zone of
- reasonableness" mandated by the NGA. See Permian Basin, supra at 767.
- What the agency has acknowledged is that automatic collection of prices up
- to the ceiling under the escalator clauses common to industry contracts
- would produce "inappropriate" market distortion, especially since the
- market price remains below the ceiling. Reply Brief for Petitioner in No.
- 89-1453, p. 12. In consequence the Commission instituted the GFN process
- to mitigate too abrupt a transition from one pricing regime to the next.
- Respondents have not sought to challenge (and we do not today consider) the
- Commission's authority to require this process, but they assert that the
- requiring of it amounts to an acknowledgment by the Commission that the new
- ceiling price is in fact unreasonable. We disagree. There is nothing
- incompatible between the belief that a price is reasonable and the belief
- that it ought not to be imposed without prior negotiations. We decline to
- disallow an otherwise lawful rate because additional safeguards accompany
- it.
- We likewise reject respondents' more fundamental objection that no
- order "deregulating" the price of old gas can be deemed just and
- reasonable. The agency's orders do not deregulate in any legally relevant
- sense. The Commission adopted an approved pricing formula, set a maximum
- price, and expressly rejected proposals that it truly deregulate by
- eliminating any ceiling for old gas whatsoever. App. 170-171. Nor can we
- conclude that deregulation results simply because a given ceiling price may
- be above the market price. United Gas Pipe Line Co. v. Mobile Gas Serv.
- Corp., 350 U. S. 332, 343 (1956); FPC v. Sierra Pacific Power Co., 350 U.
- S. 348, 353 (1956); FPC v. Texaco, Inc. 417 U. S. 380, 397 (1974).
- III
- We further hold that Order No. 451's abandonment procedures fully
- comport with the requirements set forth in MDRV 7(b) of the NGA. 15 U. S.
- C. MDRV 717(b). In particular, we reject the suggestion that this
- provision mandates individualized proceedings involving interested parties
- before a specific abandonment can take place.
- Section 7(b), which Congress retained when enacting the NGPA, states:
-
- "No natural-gas company shall abandon all or any portion of its
- facilities subject to the jurisdiction of the Commission, or any service
- rendered by means of such facilities, without the permission and approval
- of the Commission first had and obtained, after due hearing, and a finding
- by the Commission that the available supply of natural gas is depleted to
- the extent that the continuance of service is unwarranted, or that the
- present or future public convenience or necessity permit such abandonment."
- 15 U. S. C. MDRV 717(b).
-
-
- As applied to this case MDRV 7(b) prohibits a producer from abandoning its
- contractual service obligations to the purchaser unless the Commission has
- first, granted its "permission and approval" of the abandonment; second,
- made a "finding" that "present or future public convenience or necessity
- permit such abandonment"; and third, held a "hearing" that is "due." The
- Commission has taken each of these steps.
- First, Order No. 451 permits and approves the abandonment at issue.
- That approval is not specific to any single abandonment but is instead
- general, prospective, and conditional. These conditions include: failure
- by the purchaser and producer to agree to a revised price under the GFN
- procedures; execution of a new contract between the producer and a new
- purchaser; and thirty-days notice to the previous purchaser of contract
- termination. 18 CFR MDRV 270.201(c)(1) (1986). Neither respondents nor
- the Court of Appeals holding directly questions the Commission's orders for
- failing to satisfy this initial requirement. As we have previously held,
- nothing in MDRV 7(b) prevents the Commission from giving advance approval
- of abandonment. FPC v. Moss, 424 U. S. 494, 499-502 (1976). See Permian
- Basin, 390 U. S., at 776.
- Second, the Commission also made the necessary findings that "present
- or future public interest or necessity" allowed the conditional abandonment
- that it prescribed. 51 Fed. Reg., at 46785-46787. Reviewing "all relevant
- factors involved in determining the overall public interest," the
- Commission found that pre-authorized abandonment under the GFN regime would
- generally protect purchasers by allowing them to buy at market rates
- elsewhere if contracting producers insisted on the new ceiling price;
- safeguard producers by allowing them to abandon service if the contracting
- purchaser fails to come to terms; and serve the market by releasing
- previously unused reserves of old gas. See Felmont Oil Corp. and Essex
- Offshore, Inc., 33 FERC MDRV 61,333, p. 61,657 (1985), rev'd on other
- grounds sub nom. Consolidated Edison Co. of N. Y. v. FERC, 262 U. S. App.
- D. C. 222, 823 F. 2d 630 (1987). At bottom these findings demonstrate the
- agency's determination that the GFN conditions make certain matters common
- to all abandonments. Contrary to respondents' theory, MDRV 7(b) does not
- compel the agency to make "specific findings" with regard to every
- abandonment when the issues involved are general. As we held in the
- context of disability proceedings under the Social Security Act, "general
- factual issue[s] may be resolved as fairly through rulemaking" as by
- considering specific evidence when the questions under consideration are
- "not unique" to the particular case. Heckler v. Campbell, 461 U. S. 458,
- 468 (1983).
- Finally, it follows from the foregoing that the Commission discharged
- its MDRV 7(b) duty to hold a "due hearing." Before promulgating Order No.
- 451, the agency held both a notice and comment hearing and an oral hearing.
- As it correctly concluded, MDRV 7(b) required no more. Time and again,
- "[t]he Court has recognized that even where an agency's enabling statute
- expressly requires it to hold a hearing, the agency may rely on its
- rulemaking authority to determine issues that do not require case-by-case
- consideration." Heckler v. Campbell, supra, at 467; Permian Basin, supra,
- at 774-777; FPC v. Texaco Inc., 377 U. S. 33, 41-44 (1964); United States
- v. Storer Broadcasting Co., 351 U. S. 192, 205 (1956). The Commission's
- approval conditions establish, and its findings confirm, that the
- abandonment at issue here is precisely the type of issue in which "[a]
- contrary holding would require the agency continually to relitigate issues
- that may be established fairly and efficiently in a single rulemaking
- proceeding." Heckler v. Campbell, supra, at 467. See Panhandle Eastern
- Pipe Line Co. v. FERC, --- U. S. App. D. C. ---, 907 F. 2d 185, 188 (1990);
- Kansas Power & Light Co. v. FERC, 271 U. S. App. D. C. 252, 256-259, 851 F.
- 2d 1479, 1483-1486 (1988); Associated Gas Distributors v. FERC, 263 U. S.
- App. D. C. 1, 35, n. 17,, 824 F. 2d 981, 1015, n. 17 (1987), cert. denied,
- 485 U. S. 1006 (1988).
- Neither the Court of Appeals nor respondents have uncovered a
- convincing rationale for holding otherwise. Relying on United Gas Pipe
- Line Co. v. McCombs, 442 U. S. 529 (1979), the panel majority held that
- Order No. 451's prospective approval of abandonment was impermissible given
- the "practical" control the GFN process afforded producers. 885 F. 2d, at
- 221-223. McCombs, however, is inapposite since that case dealt with a
- producer who attempted to abandon with no Commission approval, finding, or
- hearing whatsoever. Nor can respondents object that the Commission made no
- provision for individual determinations under its abandonment procedures
- where appropriate. Under Order No. 451, a purchaser who objects to a given
- abandonment on the grounds that the conditions the agency has set forth
- have not been met may file a complaint with the Commission. See 18 CFR
- MDRV 385.206 (1986).
- IV
- We turn, finally, to the problem of "take-or-pay" contracts. A
- take-or-pay contract obligates a pipeline to purchase a specified volume of
- gas at a specified price and, if it is unable to do so, to pay for that
- volume. A plausible response to the gas shortages of the 1970s, this
- device has created significant dislocations in light of the oversupply of
- gas that has occurred since. Today many purchasers face disastrous
- take-or-pay liability without sufficient outlets to recoup their losses.
- The Court of Appeals cited this problem as a further reason for
- invalidating Order No. 451. Specifically, the court chastised the
- Commission for its "regrettable and unwarranted" failure to address the
- take-or-pay problem in the rulemaking under consideration. 885 F. 2d, at
- 224.
- Exactly what the court held, however, is another matter. The dissent
- viewed the majority's discussion as affirmatively ordering the Commission
- "once and for all to solve" the entire take-or-pay issue. 885 F. 2d, at
- 234 (Brown, J., dissenting). Respondents more narrowly characterize the
- holding as that the Commission should have addressed the take-or-pay
- problem at least to the extent that Order No. 451 exacerbated it. Brief
- for Respondents 67-70. We have no need to chose between these
- interpretations because the Court of Appeals erred under either view.
- The court clearly overshot the mark if it ordered the Commission to
- resolve the take-or-pay problem in this proceeding. An agency enjoys broad
- discretion in determining how best to handle related yet discrete issues in
- terms of procedures, Vermont Yankee Nuclear Power Corp. v. National
- Resources Defence Council, Inc., 435 U. S. 519 (1978), and priorities,
- Heckler v. Chaney, 470 U. S. 821, 831-832 (1985). We have expressly
- approved an earlier Commission decision to treat the take-or-pay issue
- separately where a different proceeding would generate more appropriate
- information and where the agency was addressing the question. FPC v.
- Sunray DX Oil Co., 391 U. S. 9, 49-51 (1968). The record in this case
- shows that approximately two-thirds of existing take-or-pay contracts do
- not involve old gas. We are satisfied that the agency could compile
- relevant data more effectively in a separate proceeding. We are likewise
- satisfied that "the Commission itself has taken steps to alleviate
- takeor-pay problems." Id., at 50. In promulgating Order No. 451, the
- agency explained that it had chosen not to deal with the take-or-pay matter
- directly primarily because it was addressing the matter on remand from the
- D. C. Circuit. Associated Gas Distributors v. FERC, supra. {6}
- The court likewise erred if it meant that the Commission should have
- addressed the take-or-pay problem insofar as Order No. 451 "exacerbated"
- it. This rationale does not provide a basis for invalidating the
- Commission's orders. As noted, an agency need not solve every problem
- before it in the same proceeding. This applies even where the initial
- solution to one problem has adverse consequences for another area that the
- agency was addressing. See Vermont Yankee, supra, at 543-544 (agencies are
- free to engage in multiple rulemaking "[a]bsent constitutional constraints
- or extremely compelling circumstances"). Moreover, the agency articulated
- rational grounds for concluding that Order No. 451 would do more to
- ameliorate the take-or-pay problem than worsen it. 51 Fed. Reg. 22196,
- 46783-46784. The agency reasoned that the GFN prodedures would encourage
- the renegotiation of take-or-pay provisions in contracts involving the sale
- of old gas or old gas and new gas together. 51 Fed. Reg. 22196-22197. The
- agency further noted that the release of old gas would reduce the market
- price for new gas and thus reduce the pipelines' aggregate liability. We
- are neither inclined nor prepared to second-guess the agency's reasoned
- determination in this complex area. See Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Assn. of
- United States, Inc. v. State Farm Mutual Automobile Ins. Co., 463 U. S. 29,
- 43 (1983).
- V
- We disagree with the Court of Appeals that the Commission lacked the
- authority to set a single ceiling price for old gas; possessed no power to
- authorize conditional preauthor ized abandonment of producers' obligations
- to provide old gas; or had a duty to address the take-or-pay problem more
- fully in this proceeding. Accordingly, we reverse the judgment of the
- Court of Appeals and sustain Orders No. 451 and 451-A in their entirety.
- So ordered.
-
-
- Justice Kennedy took no part in the decision in this case.
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
- ------------------------------------------------------------------------------
- 1
- The term "Commission" will refer to both the Federal Energy Regulatory
- Commission, and its predecessor the Federal Power Commission.
-
- 2
- Order No. 451 shall refer to both orders where the distinction is not
- relevant.
-
- 3
- A take-or-pay clause requires a purchasing pipeline to take a specified
- volume of gas from a producer or, if it is unable to do so, to pay for the
- specified volume. See Transco, 474 U. S. 409, 412 (1986).
-
- 4
- Section 104 in its entirety reads:
- "Ceiling price for sales of natural gas dedicated to interstate
- commerce.
-
- "(a) Application. -- In the case of natural gas committed to dedicated
- to interstate commerce on [November 8, 1978,] and for which a just and
- reasonable rate under the Natural Gas Act [15 U. S. C. MDRV 717 et seq.]
- was in effect on such date for the first sale of such natural gas, the
- maximum lawful price computed under subsection (b) shall apply to any first
- sale of such natural gas delivered during any month.
-
- "(b) Maximum lawful price. --
- "(1) General rule. -- The maximum lawful price under this section for
- any month shall be the higher of --
- "(A)(i) the just and reasonable rate, per million Btu's, established by
- the Commission which was (or would have been) applicable to the first sale
- of such natural gas on April 20, 1977, in the case of April 1977; and
- "(ii) in the case of any month thereafter, the maximum lawful price,
- per million Btu's, prescribed under this subparagraph for the preceding
- month multiplied by the monthly equivalent of the annual inflation
- adjustment factor applicable for such month, or
- "(B) any just and reasonable rate which was established by the
- Commission after April 27, 1977, and before [November 9, 1978,] and which
- is applicable to such natural gas.
- "(2) Ceiling prices may be increased if just and reasonable. -- The
- Commission may, by rule or order, prescribe a maximum lawful ceiling price,
- applicable to any first sale of any natural gas (or category thereof, as
- determined by the Commission) otherwise subject to the preceding provisions
- of this section, if such price is --
- "(A) higher than the maximum lawful price which would otherwise be
- applicable under such provisions; and
- "(B) just and reasonable within the meaning of the Natural Gas Act [15
- U. S. C. MDRV 717 et seq.]."
-
- Section 106(c), deals in almost identical language with the ceiling prices
- for sales under "rollover" contacts, which the NGPA defines as contracts
- entered into on or after November 8, 1978, for the first sale of natural
- gas that was previously subject to a contract tht expired at the end of a
- fixed term specified in the contract itself. 15 U. S. C. MDRV 3301(12). A
- reference to MDRV 104(b)(2) is here used to refer to both provisions.
-
- 5
- Even had we concluded that 15 104(b)(2) and 106(c) failed to speak
- unambiguously to the ceiling price question, we would nonetheless be
- compelled to defer to the Commission's interpretation. It follows from our
- foregoing discussion that the agency's view cannot be deemed either
- arbitrary, capricious, or manifestly contrary to the NPGA. See Chevron U.
- S. A., Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc., 467 U. S. 837,
- 843-844 (1984); K Mart Corp. v. Cartier, Inc. 486 U. S. 281, 292 (1988).
-
- 6
- The Court of Appeals for the D. C. Circuit has since invalidated the
- Commission's principal attempt at solving the problem. Associated Gas
- Distributors v. FERC, 283 U. S. App. D. C. 265, 899 F. 2d 1250 (1990). See
- also American Gas Assn. v. FERC, 912 F. 2d 1496 (1990) (approving other
- aspects of the Commission's take-or-pay proceedings). Nothing in our
- holding today precludes interested parties from petitioning the Commission
- for further rulemaking should it become apparent that the agency is no
- longer addressing the take-or-pay problem. See Panhandle Eastern Pipe Line
- Co. v. FERC, 281 U. S. App. D. C. 318, 890 F. 2d 435 (1989).
-